Boomer Retirement: Headwinds for U.S. Equity Markets?
By
The baby boom generation
born between 1946 and 1964 has had a large impact on the U.S. economy and will
continue to do so as baby boomers gradually phase from work into retirement
over the next two decades. To finance retirement, they are likely to sell off
acquired assets, especially risky equities. A looming concern is that this
massive sell-off might depress equity values. Many baby boomers have
already diversified their asset portfolios in preparation for retirement.
Still, it is disconcerting that the retirement of the baby boom generation,
which has long been expected to place downward pressure on U.S. equity values,
is beginning in earnest just as the stock market is recovering from the recent
financial crisis, potentially slowing down the pace of that recovery. This Economic Letter
examines the extent to which the aging of the U.S. population creates headwinds
for the stock market. We review statistical evidence concerning the historical
relationship between U.S. demographics and equity values, and examine the
implications of these demographic trends for the future path of equity values. Demographic
trends and stock prices: Theory Since an individual’s
financial needs and attitudes toward risk change over the life cycle, the aging
of the baby boomers and the broader shift of age distribution in the population
should have implications for capital markets (Abel 2001, 2003; Brooks 2002).
Indeed, some studies attribute the sustained asset market booms in the 1980s
and 1990s to the fact that baby boomers were entering their middle ages, the
prime period for accumulating financial assets (Bakshi and Chen 1994). However, several factors
may mitigate the effects of this demographic shift. First, demographic trends
are predictable and rational agents should anticipate the impact of these
changes on asset demand. Consequently, current asset prices should reflect the
anticipated effects of demographic changes. In addition, retired individuals
may continue to hold equities to leave to their heirs and as a source of wealth
to finance consumption in case they live longer than expected (e.g., Poterba 2001).
Foreign demand for U.S.
equities might also reduce the downward pressure on asset prices. However, the
effect is probably limited for two reasons. First, other developed nations have
populations that are aging even more rapidly than the U.S. population (Krueger
and Ludwig, 2007). Second, there is substantial evidence of home bias in equity
holdings. Individual investors typically hold disproportionate shares of
domestic assets in their portfolios. For example, in 2009, the foreign equity
holdings of U.S. investors were only 27.2% of the share of foreign equities in
global market capitalization. While the low level of international equity
diversification is still not well understood (Obstfeld and Rogoff 2001), it
suggests that foreign demand for U.S. equities is unlikely to offset price
declines resulting from a sell-off by U.S. nationals. Demographic
trends and stock prices: Some evidence To examine the historical
relationship between demographic trends and stock prices, we consider a
statistical model in which the equity price/earnings (P/E) ratio depends on a
measure of age distribution (for another example, see Geanakoplos et al. 2004).
We construct the P/E ratio based on the year-end level of the Standard &
Poor’s 500 Index adjusted for inflation and average inflation-adjusted earnings
over the past 12 months. We measure age distribution using the ratio of the
middle-age cohort, age 40–49, to the old-age cohort, age 60–69. We call this
the M/O ratio. We prefer our M/O ratio to
the M/Y ratio of middle-age to young adults, age 20–29, studied by Geanakoplos
et al. (2004). In our view, the saving and investment behavior of the old-age
cohort is more relevant for asset prices than the behavior of young adults.
Equity accumulation by young adults is low. To the extent they save, it is
primarily for housing rather than for investment in the stock market. In
contrast, individuals age 60–69 may shift their portfolios as their financial
needs and attitudes toward risk change. Eligibility for Social Security pensions
is also likely to play a first-order role in determining the life-cycle
patterns of saving, especially for old-age individuals. Figure 1 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2011/el2011-26-1.png
Figure 1 displays the P/E
and M/O ratios from 1954 to 2010. The two series appear to be highly
correlated. For example, between 1981 and 2000, as baby boomers reached their
peak working and saving ages, the M/O ratio increased from about 0.18 to about
0.74. During the same period, the P/E ratio tripled from about 8 to 24. In the
2000s, as the baby boom generation started aging and the baby bust generation
started to reach prime working and saving ages, the M/O and P/E ratios both declined
substantially. Statistical analysis confirms this correlation. In our model, we
obtain a statistically and economically significant estimate of the
relationship between the P/E and M/O ratios. We estimate that the M/O ratio
explains about 61% of the movements in the P/E ratio during the sample period.
In other words, the M/O ratio predicts long-run trends in the P/E ratio well. Demographic
headwinds for U.S. stock prices Figure 2 http://www.frbsf.org/publications/economics/letter/2011/el2011-26-2.png
This evidence suggests that
U.S. equity values are closely related to the age distribution of the
population. Since demographic trends are largely predictable, we can forecast
the path that the P/E ratio is likely to follow in the next few decades based
on the predicted M/O ratio. Figure 2 compares the actual and model-implied P/E
ratios for the sample period ending in 2010. We calculate the path for the
model-implied P/E during the sample period by feeding in actual M/O ratios. We
call the long-run path of the P/E ratio predicted by the model the “potential
P/E ratio” and designate it P/E*. Figure 2 shows that the P/E* (red dashed
line) is highly correlated with actual P/E during the sample period. What does the model say
about the future trajectory of the P/E ratio? To generate a forecast for actual
P/E from 2011 to 2030, we must first project P/E* for that period. To obtain
this future P/E* path, we calculate the projected M/O ratio from 2011 to 2030
by feeding Census Bureau projected population data into the estimated model.
Figure 2 shows that P/E* should decline persistently from about 15 in 2010 to
about 8.4 in 2025, before recovering to 9.14 in 2030. We next calculate the
probable path for the actual P/E ratio in the next two decades by introducing
an error correction model for P/E*. The actual P/E ratio frequently deviates
from the potential P/E ratio. To account for this deviation, we estimate an
error-correction model in which we assume that changes in the actual P/E ratio
depend on the previous year’s gap between P/E and P/E*. Using data from 1954 to
2010, we obtain a statistically and economically significant estimate of the
model parameters. In technical terms, the gap has a coefficient of about –0.43,
which indicates a tendency for the actual P/E ratio to converge to P/E*. This
estimate implies that, when actual P/E exceeds potential P/E by 1%, the actual
P/E ratio should fall by 0.43% within a year. Given the projected path for P/E*
and the estimated convergence process, we find that the actual P/E ratio should
decline from about 15 in 2010 to about 8.3 in 2025 before recovering to about 9
in 2030. We are also interested in
forecasting the potential path for stock prices. Since we have forecast a path
for the P/E ratio, predicting stock prices is straightforward if we can project
earnings, the E part of the ratio. For this purpose, we assume that, in the
next decade, real earnings will grow steadily at the same average 3.42% annual
rate by which they grew from 1954 to 2010. To obtain real earnings, we deflate
nominal earnings by the consumer price index. The model-generated path
for real stock prices implied by demographic trends is quite bearish. Real
stock prices follow a downward trend until 2021, cumulatively declining about
13% relative to 2010. The subsequent recovery is quite slow. Indeed, real stock
prices are not expected to return to their 2010 level until 2027. On the
brighter side, as the M/O ratio rebounds in 2025, we should expect a strong
stock price recovery. By 2030, our calculations suggest that the real value of
equities will be about 20% higher than in 2010. Conclusion Despite theoretical
ambiguities, U.S. equity values have been closely related to demographic trends
in the past half century. There has been a tight correlation between population
dependency ratios, such as the M/O ratio, and the P/E ratio of the U.S. stock
market. In the context of the impending retirement of baby boomers over the
next two decades, this correlation portends poorly for equity values. Moreover,
the demographic changes related to the retirement of the baby boom generation
are well known. This suggests that market participants may anticipate that
equities will perform poorly in the future, an expectation that can potentially
depress current stock prices. In that sense, these demographic shifts may
present headwinds today for the stock market’s recovery from the financial
crisis. Still, theoretical ambiguities
make such projections far from certain. In considering the future trajectory of
equity values, we have examined a single factor—the M/O ratio. Needless to say,
many other factors may drive demand for stock. For example, researchers have
correlated long swings in P/E ratios with relative volatility in bond and
equity markets and long-term bond yields (e.g., Lansing 2004). In addition,
foreign investor taste for U.S. assets may change. Foreign countries hold large
quantities of U.S. securities, and foreign agents, such as sovereign wealth
funds, may alter their mix of U.S. assets in favor of equities. China and other
emerging market countries may relax capital controls, which would allow their
nationals to invest in U.S. equity markets. These factors could potentially
alleviate the adverse impact of U.S. demographic trends on stock markets. References Abel, Andrew B.
2001. “Will Bequests Attenuate the Predicted Meltdown in Stock Prices When Baby
Boomers Retire?” Review of Economics and Statistics 83(4), pp.
589–595. Abel, Andrew B.
2003. “The Effects of a Baby Boom on Stock Prices and Capital Accumulation in
the Presence of Social Security.” Econometrica 71(2), pp. 551–578. Bakshi, Gurdip
S., and Zhiwu Chen. 1994. “Baby Boom, Population Aging, and Capital Markets.” The
Journal of Business 67(2), pp. 165–202. Brooks, Robin.
2002. “Asset-Market Effects of the Baby Boom and Social-Security Reform.” American
Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 92(2), pp. 402–406. Geanakoplos,
John, Michael Magill, and Martine Quinzii. 2004. “Demography and the Long-Run
Predictability of the Stock Market.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
1, pp. 241–307. Krueger, Dirk,
and Alexander Ludwig. 2007. “On the Consequences of Demographic Change for
Rates of Returns to Capital, and the Distribution of Wealth and Welfare.” Journal
of Monetary Economics 54, pp. 49–87. Lansing, Kevin
J. 2004. “Inflation-Induced Valuation Errors in the Stock Market.”
FRBSF Economic Letter 2004-30 (October 29). Obstfeld,
Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 2001. “The Six Major Puzzles in International
Macroeconomics: Is There a Common Cause?” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual
2000, eds. Ben Bernanke and Kenneth Rogoff. Cambridge: NBER and MIT Press. Poterba, James
M. 2001. “Demographic Structure and Asset Returns.” Review of Economics and
Statistics 83(4), pp. 565–584
P/E ratio and M/O ratio
Projected P/E ratio from demographic trends